Sinh viên mới ra trường

Ðề: Sinh viên mới ra trường

Sinh viên kế toán mới ra trường thì không thể có kinh nghiệm thực tế được. Hiện nay các bạn ấy có 2 lựa chọn

1. Nhận mức lương thực tập một thời gian để học hỏi kinh nghiệm nhưng rất vất vả và mất nhiều thời gian 1 đến 2 năm
2. Học khóa *************** 2, 3 tháng mất học phí khoảng 2 triệu ở trung tâm có uy tín thu được kha khá kinh nghiệm mà bình thường phải mất 2 năm mới tích luỹ được

Bạn chọn cách nào?

Doanh nghiệp bây giờ họ cần năng lực làm việc nên họ ưu tiên những người biết làm việc hơn là những người vào học hỏi kinh nghiệm cho nên tốt nhất là chọn cách 2 mất chi phí ban đầu nhưng mang lại hiệu quả cho mình hơn là lãng phí 1, 2 năm đi học hỏi kinh nghiệm

Mình chọn cách 2 mình học khóa thực tế ở Công ty kế toán Hà Nội rồi ở đó đào tạo kỹ năng và nghiệp vụ khá ổn đó bạn nào muốn tìm hiểu thêm thì có thể liên hệ theo số này 0983514093
làm kế toán nghèo chết , mức lương tăng thấp nhất
đang học đh nghành kế toán năm II
cũng rầu quá chắc ra trường rồi học lên cao học quản trị kinh doanh , ko muốn theo kế toán ( ngồi có 1 chỗ chán ) , định học bằng ACCA chắc cũng bỏ luôn học MBA cho rầu
 
Ðề: Sinh viên mới ra trường

Mình thấy có các trung tâm dạy kế toán, sau mỗi khóa học của họ họ sẽ làm cho cái giấy chứng nhận đã làm việc ở đấy 2 năm. Ko biết có tác dụng không?? với lại thấy đi học thế kinh nghiệm thực tế cũng lên mà. Mình chưa ra trường lên cũng không rõ lắm

a.c.e ai có kinh nghiệm tư vấn cho mình mấy trung tâm dạy kế toán uy tín và giá rẻ ở HN đc ko?
có lẽ mình cũng phải đi học 1 khóa thôi. hic:nheo:
 
Ðề: Sinh viên mới ra trường

Xin thưa , tớ đã có chứng chỉ kế toán trưởng và chứng nhận 2 năm kinh nghiệm :danghi:.

Nhà tuyển dụng yêu cầu 2 năm kinh nghiệm từ khi bạn tốt nghiệp.

Đúng là khi xin việc, cơ hội và sự may mắn luôn đi kèm với nhau :nongqua:



hic.
Thế khi là sinh viên mà đi thực tập luôn, khi ra trường khai là có kinh nghiệm nó ko chấp nhận ak " nhilanthan "? cứ phải yêu cầu sau khi tốt nghiệp ak? nản! Mình sợ bị thế nên đi từ giờ, kiểu này vô tác dụng rùi! hix
 
Ðề: Sinh viên mới ra trường

Mình học cao đẳng công nghiệp Huế chuyên ngành kế toán, mới thi tốt nghiệp xong ngày 11.06.2012. Thi xong ăn chơi thả phanh và học tiếng anh đến ngày 20.7 thì bắt đầu vác hành lý vào Đà Nẵng tìm việc làm, vì định hướng trước sẽ không làm việc ở Huế nên mặc dù không biết có việc gì làm không, vẫn cứ vào Đà Nẵng đã tính sau. Thời gian đầu vào, đi tìm việc, phải nói là nản cực độ, nhưng cũng may là tranh thủ học tiếng anh ở nhà nên nó cũng đỡ chán, tối tối nói chuyện vs bạn bè bằng tiếng anh trên skype cũng làm mình đỡ nhớ nhà, bạn bè cỗ vũ động viên. Cầm bằng Giỏi trên tay, có thể giao tiếp tốt bằng tiếng anh nhưng xin việc rất khó, có đôi lúc nản quá định đi làm công nhân vì xác định con đường tìm việc là lâu dài, và mình cần có tiền để trang trải cho quá trình tìm việc. Rồi đi phỏng vấn làm tổng đài viên cho công ty Mobitechs, lúc phỏng vấn xong thì có cuộc gọi từ nhà hàng OdeV-chỗ làm hiện tại gọi tới, bảo đem hồ sơ tới phỏng vấn, tới phỏng vấn bằng tiếng anh, thấy ok nên nhận vào, mức lương cũng tuơng đối cao, công việc đầu tiên là làm thu ngân, hằng ngày tiếp xúc với người nước ngoài, cuộc sống của mình bây giờ tiếp xúc vs họ nhiều hơn là ng việt. Làm thu ngân 1 thời gian, thấy chán, đòi nghĩ việc để được làm đúng chuyên ngành, giờ thì họ chuyển mình lên bộ phận kế toán là về kế toán mua hàng. Đồng thời cũng kiêm luôn làm thu ngân, 1 mình phải làm 1 núi việc.......1 ngày làm 12 tiếng....đôi khi thấy nản và mệt lắm, định quit cho xong, nhưng nghĩ lại môi trường làm việc ở đây ai cũng tốt với mình, mình cảm thấy vui vẻ nên k nỡ ra đi.
 
Ðề: Sinh viên mới ra trường

Thế khi là sinh viên mà đi thực tập luôn, khi ra trường khai là có kinh nghiệm nó ko chấp nhận ak " nhilanthan "? cứ phải yêu cầu sau khi tốt nghiệp ak? nản! Mình sợ bị thế nên đi từ giờ, kiểu này vô tác dụng rùi! hix

Lạc quan lên mọi người. Đúng là khi đi xin việc thì cty nào chẳng muốn tuyển được người có kinh nghiệm. Nghe thấy sinh viên là nghĩ ngay phải đào tạo, chưa biết làm gì nên họ ngại. Nhưng nếu sinh viên đã biết làm, tối thiểu với dân kế toán phải biết được trong tháng làm gì, cuối tháng làm gì, có biết cân đối chi phí hay không, biết làm BCTC hay không. đã va vấp thực tế chưa.
Nếu các bạn biết làm và nắm rõ công việc của kế toán thì sẽ rất khả quan hơn khi đi xin việc đấy. Các bạn có thể tự tin nói với nhà tuyển dụng: Nếu tuyển được người có kinh nghiệm thì mức lương sẽ là lương chính thức hoặc tương đương, cty bạn sẽ không mất công đào tạo nhiều. Nhưng nếu tuyển sinh viên biết làm những công việc đó rồi đảm bảo là chỉ cần hướng dẫn về hàng hóa và qui trình công ty để thích nghi công việc với 1 mức lương thử việc cho sinh viên (đương nhiên bạn sẽ chịu thiệt 1 2 tháng) thì cty bạn sẽ chọn ai, nếu bạn tự tin được như vậy thì không thể không lọt vào tầm ngắm của nhà tuyển dụng được
Đa phần các bạn sv thường tự ti khi đi xin việc.
Trong trường thì ít va vấp thực tế nên khi tới test 1 số nghiệp vụ trên hóa đơn, trường hợp thực tế thì chỉ tròn mắt nhìn lại thôi nên cơ hội bị mất.
Các bạn cứ suy nghĩ thật kỹ là kiến thức của mình tới đâu, có thể làm gì và không ngừng học hỏi, đừng bi quan mọi người a
Còn ở trung tâm có xác nhận thực nhưng mà so với năm các bạn ra trường thì bị lệch
Trung tâm mình ít khi làm xác nhận mà hầu hết là liên hệ với các công ty làm dịch vụ, các bạn có thể nói là làm thêm ở đó, phụ việc kế toán hoặc nhận kê khai thuế làm tại nhà trong thời gian đi học( đương nhiên là khi học hết môn chuyên ngành mới làm được nhé).
Kinh nghiệm có thể là vài tháng nhưng mà từ năm này sang năm kia các bạn cũng nói là 2 năm, không sao hết, miễn sao được vào vòng trong nhé

Chúc các bạn may mắn
 
Ðề: Sinh viên mới ra trường

In economics, a recession is a business cycle contraction, a general slowdown in economic activity.[1][2] Macroeconomic indicators such as GDP, employment, investment spending, capacity utilization, household income, business profits, and inflation fall, while bankruptcies and the unemployment rate rise.
Recessions generally occur when there is a widespread drop in spending, often following an adverse supply shock or the bursting of an economic bubble. Governments usually respond to recessions by adopting expansionary macroeconomic policies, such as increasing money supply, increasing government spending and decreasing taxation.
Contents [hide]
1 Definition
2 Attributes
2.1 Type of recession or shape
2.2 Psychological aspects
2.3 Balance sheet recession
2.4 Liquidity trap
2.5 Paradoxes of thrift and deleveraging
3 Predictors
4 Government responses
5 Stock market
6 Politics
7 Impacts
7.1 Unemployment
7.2 Business
7.3 Social effects
8 History
8.1 Global
8.2 United Kingdom
8.3 United States
8.4 Late 2000s
8.4.1 United States
8.4.2 Other countries
9 See also
10 References
11 External links
[edit]Definition

In a 1975 New York Times article, economic statistician Julius Shiskin suggested several rules of thumb for defining a recession, one of which was "two down consecutive quarters of GDP".[3] In time, the other rules of thumb were forgotten. Some economists prefer a definition of a 1.5% rise in unemployment within 12 months.[4]
In the United States, the Business Cycle Dating Committee of the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) is generally seen as the authority for dating US recessions. The NBER defines an economic recession as: "a significant decline in economic activity spread across the economy, lasting more than a few months, normally visible in real GDP, real income, employment, industrial production, and wholesale-retail sales."[5] Almost universally, academics, economists, policy makers, and businesses defer to the determination by the NBER for the precise dating of a recession's onset and end.
In the UK recessions are generally defined as 2 successive quarters of negative growth (or 6 months).[6]
[edit]Attributes

This section requires expansion. (March 2009)
A recession has many attributes that can occur simultaneously and includes declines in component measures of economic activity (GDP) such as consumption, investment, government spending, and net export activity. These summary measures reflect underlying drivers such as employment levels and skills, household savings rates, corporate investment decisions, interest rates, demographics, and government policies.
Economist Richard C. Koo wrote that under ideal conditions, a country's economy should have the household sector as net savers and the corporate sector as net borrowers, with the government budget nearly balanced and net exports near zero.[7][8] When these relationships become imbalanced, recession can develop within the country or create pressure for recession in another country. Policy responses are often designed to drive the economy back towards this ideal state of balance.
A severe (GDP down by 10%) or prolonged (three or four years) recession is referred to as an economic depression, although some argue that their causes and cures can be different.[4] As an informal shorthand, economists sometimes refer to different recession shapes, such as V-shaped, U-shaped, L-shaped and W-shaped recessions.
[edit]Type of recession or shape
Main article: Recession shapes
The type and shape of recessions are distinctive. In the US, V-shaped, or short-and-sharp contractions followed by rapid and sustained recovery, occurred in 1954 and 1990–91; U-shaped (prolonged slump) in 1974–75, and W-shaped, or double-dip recessions in 1949 and 1980–82. Japan’s 1993–94 recession was U-shaped and its 8-out-of-9 quarters of contraction in 1997–99 can be described as L-shaped. Korea, Hong Kong and South-east Asia experienced U-shaped recessions in 1997–98, although Thailand’s eight consecutive quarters of decline should be termed L-shaped.[9]
[edit]Psychological aspects
Recessions have psychological and confidence aspects. For example, if the expectation develops that economic activity will slow, firms may decide to reduce employment levels and save money rather than invest. Such expectations can create a self-reinforcing downward cycle, bringing about or worsening a recession.[10] Consumer confidence is one measure used to evaluate economic sentiment.[11] The term animal spirits has been used to describe the psychological factors underlying economic activity. Economist Robert J. Shiller wrote that the term "...refers also to the sense of trust we have in each other, our sense of fairness in economic dealings, and our sense of the extent of corruption and bad faith. When animal spirits are on ebb, consumers do not want to spend and businesses do not want to make capital expenditures or hire people."[12]
[edit]Balance sheet recession
The bursting of a real estate or financial asset price bubble can cause a recession. For example, economist Richard Koo wrote that Japan's "Great Recession" that began in 1990 was a "balance sheet recession." It was triggered by a collapse in land and stock prices, which caused Japanese firms to have negative equity, meaning their assets were worth less than their liabilities. Despite zero interest rates and expansion of the money supply to encourage borrowing, Japanese corporations in aggregate opted to pay down their debts from their own business earnings rather than borrow to invest as firms typically do. Corporate investment, a key demand component of GDP, fell enormously (22% of GDP) between 1990 and its peak decline in 2003. Japanese firms overall became net savers after 1998, as opposed to borrowers. Koo argues that it was massive fiscal stimulus (borrowing and spending by the government) that offset this decline and enabled Japan to maintain its level of GDP. In his view, this avoided a U.S. type Great Depression, in which U.S. GDP fell by 46%. He argued that monetary policy was ineffective because there was limited demand for funds while firms paid down their liabilities. In a balance sheet recession, GDP declines by the amount of debt repayment and un-borrowed individual savings, leaving government stimulus spending as the primary remedy.[7][8][13][14]
Paul Krugman discussed the balance sheet recession concept during 2010, agreeing with Koo's situation assessment and view that sustained deficit spending when faced with a balance sheet recession would be appropriate. However, Krugman argued that monetary policy could also affect savings behavior, as inflation or credible promises of future inflation (generating negative real interest rates) would encourage less savings. In other words, people would tend to spend more rather than save if they believe inflation is on the horizon. In more technical terms, Krugman argues that the private sector savings curve is elastic even during a balance sheet recession (responsive to changes in real interest rates) disagreeing with Koo's view that it is inelastic (non-responsive to changes in real interest rates).[15][16]
A July 2012 survey of balance sheet recession research reported that consumer demand and employment are affected by household leverage levels. Both durable and non-durable goods consumption declined as households moved from low to high leverage with the decline in property values experienced during the subprime mortgage crisis. Further, reduced consumption due to higher household leverage can account for a significant decline in employment levels. Policies that help reduce mortgage debt or household leverage could therefore have stimulative effects.[17][18]
[edit]Liquidity trap
A liquidity trap is a Keynesian theory that a situation can develop in which interest rates reach near zero (ZIRP) yet do not effectively stimulate the economy. In theory, near-zero interest rates should encourage firms and consumers to borrow and spend. However, if too many individuals or corporations focus on saving or paying down debt rather than spending, lower interest rates have less effect on investment and consumption behavior; the lower interest rates are like "pushing on a string." Economist Paul Krugman described the U.S. 2009 recession and Japan's lost decade as liquidity traps. One remedy to a liquidity trap is expanding the money supply via quantitative easing or other techniques in which money is effectively printed to purchase assets, thereby creating inflationary expectations that cause savers to begin spending again. Government stimulus spending and mercantilist policies to stimulate exports and reduce imports are other techniques to stimulate demand.[19] He estimated in March 2010 that developed countries representing 70% of the world's GDP were caught in a liquidity trap.[20]
[edit]Paradoxes of thrift and deleveraging
Behavior that may be optimal for an individual (e.g., saving more during adverse economic conditions) can be detrimental if too many individuals pursue the same behavior, as ultimately one person's consumption is another person's income. Too many consumers attempting to save (or pay down debt) simultaneously is called the paradox of thrift and can cause or deepen a recession. Economist Hyman Minsky also described a "paradox of deleveraging" as financial institutions that have too much leverage (debt relative to equity) cannot all de-leverage simultaneously without significant declines in the value of their assets.[21]
During April 2009, U.S. Federal Reserve Vice Chair Janet Yellen discussed these paradoxes: "Once this massive credit crunch hit, it didn’t take long before we were in a recession. The recession, in turn, deepened the credit crunch as demand and employment fell, and credit losses of financial institutions surged. Indeed, we have been in the grips of precisely this adverse feedback loop for more than a year. A process of balance sheet deleveraging has spread to nearly every corner of the economy. Consumers are pulling back on purchases, especially on durable goods, to build their savings. Businesses are cancelling planned investments and laying off workers to preserve cash. And, financial institutions are shrinking assets to bolster capital and improve their chances of weathering the current storm. Once again, Minsky understood this dynamic. He spoke of the paradox of deleveraging, in which precautions that may be smart for individuals and firms—and indeed essential to return the economy to a normal state—nevertheless magnify the distress of the economy as a whole."[21]
[edit]Predictors

Although there are no completely reliable predictors, the following are regarded to be possible predictors.[22]
Inverted yield curve,[23] the model developed by economist Jonathan H. Wright, uses yields on 10-year and three-month Treasury securities as well as the Fed's overnight funds rate.[24] Another model developed by Federal Reserve Bank of New York economists uses only the 10-year/three-month spread. It is, however, not a definite indicator;[25]
The three-month change in the unemployment rate and initial jobless claims.[26]
Index of Leading (Economic) Indicators (includes some of the above indicators).[27]
Lowering of asset prices, such as homes and financial assets, or high personal and corporate debt levels.
[edit]Government responses

This section requires expansion. (March 2009)
See also: Stabilization policy
Most mainstream economists believe that recessions are caused by inadequate aggregate demand in the economy, and favor the use of expansionary macroeconomic policy during recessions. Strategies favored for moving an economy out of a recession vary depending on which economic school the policymakers follow. Monetarists would favor the use of expansionary monetary policy, while Keynesian economists may advocate increased government spending to spark economic growth. Supply-side economists may suggest tax cuts to promote business capital investment. When interest rates reach the boundary of an interest rate of zero percent conventional monetary policy can no longer be used and government must use other measures to stimulate recovery. Keynesians argue that fiscal policy, tax cuts or increased government spending, will work when monetary policy fails. Spending is more effective because of its larger multiplier but tax cuts take effect faster.
For example, Paul Krugman wrote in December 2010 that significant, sustained government spending was necessary because indebted households were paying down debts and unable to carry the U.S. economy as they had previously: "The root of our current troubles lies in the debt American families ran up during the Bush-era housing bubble...highly indebted Americans not only can’t spend the way they used to, they’re having to pay down the debts they ran up in the bubble years. This would be fine if someone else were taking up the slack. But what’s actually happening is that some people are spending much less while nobody is spending more — and this translates into a depressed economy and high unemployment. What the government should be doing in this situation is spending more while the private sector is spending less, supporting employment while those debts are paid down. And this government spending needs to be sustained..."[28]
[edit]Stock market

Some recessions have been anticipated by stock market declines. In Stocks for the Long Run, Siegel mentions that since 1948, ten recessions were preceded by a stock market decline, by a lead time of 0 to 13 months (average 5.7 months), while ten stock market declines of greater than 10% in the DJIA were not followed by a recession.[29]
The real-estate market also usually weakens before a recession.[30] However real-estate declines can last much longer than recessions.[31]
Since the business cycle is very hard to predict, Siegel argues that it is not possible to take advantage of economic cycles for timing investments. Even the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) takes a few months to determine if a peak or trough has occurred in the US.[32]
During an economic decline, high yield stocks such as fast moving consumer goods, pharmaceuticals, and tobacco tend to hold up better.[33] However when the economy starts to recover and the bottom of the market has passed (sometimes identified on charts as a MACD[34]), growth stocks tend to recover faster. There is significant disagreement about how health care and utilities tend to recover.[35] Diversifying one's portfolio into international stocks may provide some safety; however, economies that are closely correlated with that of the U.S. may also be affected by a recession in the U.S.[36]
There is a view termed the halfway rule[37] according to which investors start discounting an economic recovery about halfway through a recession. In the 16 U.S. recessions since 1919, the average length has been 13 months, although the recent recessions have been shorter. Thus if the 2008 recession followed the average, the downturn in the stock market would have bottomed around November 2008. The actual US stock market bottom of the 2008 recession was in March 2009.
[edit]Politics

Generally an administration gets credit or blame for the state of economy during its time.[38] This has caused disagreements about when a recession actually started.[39] In an economic cycle, a downturn can be considered a consequence of an expansion reaching an unsustainable state, and is corrected by a brief decline. Thus it is not easy to isolate the causes of specific phases of the cycle.
The 1981 recession is thought to have been caused by the tight-money policy adopted by Paul Volcker, chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, before Ronald Reagan took office. Reagan supported that policy. Economist Walter Heller, chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers in the 1960s, said that "I call it a Reagan-Volcker-Carter recession.[40] The resulting taming of inflation did, however, set the stage for a robust growth period during Reagan's administration.
Economists usually teach that to some degree recession is unavoidable, and its causes are not well understood. Consequently, modern government administrations attempt to take steps, also not agreed upon, to soften a recession.
[edit]Impacts

[edit]Unemployment
Unemployment is particularly high during a recession. Many economists working within the neoclassical paradigm argue that there is a natural rate of unemployment which, when subtracted from the actual rate of unemployment, can be used to calculate the negative GDP gap during a recession. In other words, unemployment will never reach 0 percent and thus is not a negative indicator of the health of an economy unless it is above the "natural rate," in which case it corresponds directly to a loss in gross domestic product, or GDP.[41]

The examples and perspective in this article deal primarily with the United Kingdom and do not represent a worldwide view of the subject. Please improve this article and discuss the issue on the talk page. (August 2011)
The full impact of a recession on employment may not be felt for several quarters. Research in Britain shows that low-skilled, low-educated workers and the young are most vulnerable to unemployment[42] in a downturn. After recessions in Britain in the 1980s and 1990s, it took five years for unemployment to fall back to its original levels.[43] Many companies often expect employment discrimination claims to rise during a recession.[44]
[edit]Business
Productivity tends to fall in the early stages of a recession, then rises again as weaker firms close. The variation in profitability between firms rises sharply. Recessions have also provided opportunities for anti-competitive mergers, with a negative impact on the wider economy: the suspension of competition policy in the United States in the 1930s may have extended the Great Depression.[43]
[edit]Social effects
The living standards of people dependent on wages and salaries are more affected by recessions than those who rely on fixed incomes or welfare benefits. The loss of a job is known to have a negative impact on the stability of families, and individuals' health and well-being.[43]
[edit]History

[edit]Global
There is no commonly accepted definition of a global recession, although the International Monetary Fund (IMF) regards periods when global growth is less than 3% to be global recessions.[45] The IMF estimates that global recessions seem to occur over a cycle lasting between 8 and 10 years.[citation needed] During what the IMF terms the past three global recessions of the last three decades, global per capita output growth was zero or negative.[46]
Economists at the IMF state that a global recession would take a slowdown in global growth to three percent or less. By this measure, four periods since 1985 qualify: 1990–1993, 1998, 2001–2002 and 2008–2009.
[edit]United Kingdom
Main article: List of recessions in the United Kingdom
The most recent recession to affect the United kingdom was the late-2000s recession.
[edit]United States
Main article: List of recessions in the United States

This section duplicates, in whole or part, the scope of other article(s) or section(s).
Please discuss this issue on the talk page and conform with Wikipedia's Manual of Style by replacing the section with a link and a summary of the repeated material, or by spinning off the repeated text into an article in its own right.
According to economists, since 1854, the U.S. has encountered 32 cycles of expansions and contractions, with an average of 17 months of contraction and 38 months of expansion.[5] However, since 1980 there have been only eight periods of negative economic growth over one fiscal quarter or more,[47] and four periods considered recessions:
July 1981 – November 1982: 14 months
July 1990 – March 1991: 8 months
March 2001 – November 2001: 8 months
December 2007 – June 2009: 18 months[48][49]
For the past three recessions, the NBER decision has approximately conformed with the definition involving two consecutive quarters of decline. While the 2001 recession did not involve two consecutive quarters of decline, it was preceded by two quarters of alternating decline and weak growth.[47]
[edit]Late 2000s
Main article: Late-2000s recession
Official economic data shows that a substantial number of nations are in recession as of early 2009. The US entered a recession at the end of 2007,[50] and 2008 saw many other nations follow suit. The US recession of 2007 ended in June, 2009[51] as the nation entered the current economic recovery.
[edit]United States
The United States housing market correction (a possible consequence of United States housing bubble) and subprime mortgage crisis has significantly contributed to a recession.
The 2008/2009 recession saw private consumption fall for the first time in nearly 20 years. This indicates the depth and severity of the current recession. With consumer confidence so low, recovery will take a long time. Consumers in the U.S. have been hard hit by the current recession, with the value of their houses dropping and their pension savings decimated on the stock market. Not only have consumers watched their wealth being eroded – they are now fearing for their jobs as unemployment rises.[52]
U.S. employers shed 63,000 jobs in February 2008,[53] the most in five years. Former Federal Reserve chairman Alan Greenspan said on 6 April 2008 that "There is more than a 50 percent chance the United States could go into recession."[54] On 1 October, the Bureau of Economic Analysis reported that an additional 156,000 jobs had been lost in September. On 29 April 2008, nine US states were declared by Moody's to be in a recession. In November 2008, employers eliminated 533,000 jobs, the largest single month loss in 34 years.[55] For 2008, an estimated 2.6 million U.S. jobs were eliminated.[56]
The unemployment rate in the US grew to 8.5 percent in March 2009, and there were 5.1 million job losses until March 2009 since the recession began in December 2007.[57] That was about five million more people unemployed compared to just a year prior,[58] which was the largest annual jump in the number of unemployed persons since the 1940s.[59]
Although the US Economy grew in the first quarter by 1%,[60][61] by June 2008 some analysts stated that due to a protracted credit crisis and "rampant inflation in commodities such as oil, food and steel", the country was nonetheless in a recession.[62] The third quarter of 2008 brought on a GDP retraction of 0.5%[63] the biggest decline since 2001. The 6.4% decline in spending during Q3 on non-durable goods, like clothing and food, was the largest since 1950.[64]
A 17 Nov 2008 report from the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia based on the survey of 51 forecasters, suggested that the recession started in April 2008 and will last 14 months.[65] They project real GDP declining at an annual rate of 2.9% in the fourth quarter and 1.1% in the first quarter of 2009. These forecasts represent significant downward revisions from the forecasts of three months ago.
A 1 December 2008, report from the National Bureau of Economic Research stated that the U.S. has been in a recession since December 2007 (when economic activity peaked), based on a number of measures including job losses, declines in personal income, and declines in real GDP.[66] By July 2009 a growing number of economists believed that the recession may have ended.[67][68] The National Bureau of Economic Research announced on 20 September 2010 that the 2008/2009 recession ended in June 2009, making it the longest recession since World War II.[69]
[edit]Other countries
This section does not cite any references or sources. (February 2008)
Many other countries, particularly in Europe, have undergone decreasing rates of GDP growth. Some countries have been able to avoid a recession but have still experienced slower economic activity, such as China. Australia was able to maintain positive growth throughout the late-2000s (decade) recession.
[edit]See also

Buffer Theory
Economic depression
Economic stagnation
Stagflation
Causes
Crisis theory
Currency crisis
Financial crisis
Overproduction
Underconsumption
Effects
Bankruptcies
Credit crunches
Deflation (or disinflation)
Foreclosures
Unemployment
Specific:
Great Depression – August 1929 to September 1939: the longest (and most severe) recession of the 20th century
Financial crisis of 2007-2010- current recession
List of recessions in the United States – a list of important recessions in the United States
 

CẨM NANG KẾ TOÁN TRƯỞNG


Liên hệ: 090.6969.247

KÊNH YOUTUBE DKT

Cách làm file Excel quản lý lãi vay

Đăng ký kênh nhé cả nhà

SÁCH QUYẾT TOÁN THUẾ


Liên hệ: 090.6969.247

Top